08/06/2012 By

When
the euro was introduced, regulators allowed banks to buy unlimited
amounts of government bonds without setting aside any equity capital,
and the ECB discounted all eurozone government bonds on equal terms.
Commercial banks found it advantageous to accumulate weaker countries’
bonds to earn a few extra basis points, which caused interest rates to
converge across the eurozone. Germany, struggling with the burdens of
reunification, undertook structural reforms and became more competitive.
Other countries enjoyed housing and consumption booms on the back of
cheap credit, making them less competitive.
Then
came the crash of 2008. Governments had to bail out their banks. Some
of them found themselves in the position of a developing country that
had become heavily indebted in a currency that it did not control.
Reflecting the divergence in economic performance, Europe became divided
into creditor and debtor countries.
When
financial markets discovered that supposedly riskless government bonds
might be forced into default, they raised risk premiums dramatically.
This rendered potentially insolvent commercial banks, whose balance
sheets were loaded with such bonds, giving rise to Europe’s twin
sovereign-debt and banking crisis.
The
eurozone is now replicating how the global financial system dealt with
such crises in 1982 and again in 1997. In both cases, the international
authorities inflicted hardship on the periphery in order to protect the
center; now Germany is unknowingly playing the same role.
The
details differ, but the idea is the same: creditors are shifting the
entire burden of adjustment onto debtors, while the “center” avoids its
own responsibility for the imbalances. Interestingly, the terms “center”
and “periphery” have crept into usage almost unnoticed. Yet, in the
euro crisis, the center’s responsibility is even greater than it was in
1982 or 1997: it designed a flawed currency system and failed to correct
the defects. In the 1980’s, Latin America suffered a lost decade; a
similar fate now awaits Europe.
At
the onset of the crisis, a breakup of the euro was inconceivable: the
assets and liabilities denominated in a common currency were so
intermingled that a breakup would have led to an uncontrollable
meltdown. But, as the crisis has progressed, the financial system has
become increasingly reordered along national lines. This trend has
gathered momentum in recent months. The ECB’s long-term refinancing
operation enabled Spanish and Italian banks to buy their own countries’
bonds and earn a large spread. Simultaneously, banks gave preference to
shedding assets outside their national borders, and risk managers try to
match assets and liabilities at home, rather than within the eurozone
as a whole.
If
this continued for a few years, a euro breakup would become possible
without a meltdown, but it would leave the creditor countries with large
claims against debtor countries, which would be difficult to collect.
In addition to intergovernmental transfers and guarantees, the
Bundesbank’s claims against peripheral countries’ central banks within
the Target2 clearing system totaled €644 billion ($804 billion) on April
30, and the amount is growing exponentially, owing to capital flight.
So
the crisis keeps growing. Tensions in financial markets have hit new
highs. Most telling is that Britain, which retained control of its
currency, enjoys the lowest yields in its history, while the risk
premium on Spanish bonds is at a new high.
The
real economy of the eurozone is declining, while Germany is booming.
This means that the divergence is widening. The political and social
dynamics are also working toward disintegration. Public opinion, as
expressed in recent election results, is increasingly opposed to
austerity, and this trend is likely to continue until the policy is
reversed. Something has to give.
In
my judgment, the authorities have a three-month window during which
they could still correct their mistakes and reverse current trends. That
would require some extraordinary policy measures to return conditions
closer to normal, and they must conform to existing treaties, which
could then be revised in a calmer atmosphere to prevent recurrence of
imbalances.
It
is difficult, but not impossible, to identify some extraordinary
measures that would meet these tough requirements. They would have to
tackle the banking and the sovereign-debt problems simultaneously,
without neglecting to reduce divergences in competitiveness.
The
eurozone needs a banking union: a European deposit-insurance scheme in
order to stem capital flight, a European source for financing bank
recapitalization, and eurozone-wide supervision and regulation. The
heavily indebted countries need relief on their financing costs. There
are various ways to provide it, but they all require Germany’s active
support.
That
is where the blockage is. German authorities are working feverishly to
come up with a set of proposals in time for the European Union summit at
the end of June, but all signs suggest that they will offer only the
minimum on which the various parties can agree – implying, once again,
only temporary relief.
But
we are at an inflection point. The Greek crisis is liable to come to a
climax in the fall, even if the election produces a government that is
willing to abide by Greece’s current agreement with its creditors. By
that time, the German economy will also be weakening, so that Chancellor
Angela Merkel will find it even more difficult than today to persuade
the German public to accept additional European responsibilities.
Barring
an accident like the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy, Germany is likely to
do enough to hold the euro together, but the EU will become something
very different from the open society that once fired people’s
imagination. The division between debtor and creditor countries will
become permanent, with Germany dominating and the periphery becoming a
depressed hinterland.
This
will inevitably arouse suspicion about Germany’s role in Europe – but
any comparison with Germany’s past is quite inappropriate. The current
situation is due not to a deliberate plan, but to the lack of one. It is
a tragedy of policy errors. Germany is a well-functioning democracy
with an overwhelming majority for an open society. When the German
people become aware of the consequences – one hopes not too late – they
will want to correct the defects in the euro’s design.
It
is clear what is needed: a European fiscal authority that is able and
willing to reduce the debt burden of the periphery, as well as a banking
union. Debt relief could take various forms other than Eurobonds, and
would be conditional on debtors abiding by the fiscal compact.
Withdrawing all or part of the relief in case of nonperformance would be
a powerful protection against moral hazard. It is up to Germany to live
up to the leadership responsibilities thrust upon it by its own
success.
Source: Project Syndicate [accessed 9/6/2012]
No comments:
Post a Comment